Imagine a world with no ads or paywalls. A world where open-source software gets the same level of funding as proprietary software. A world where people can freely reuse ideas and music without paying royalties. A world where people get paid for writing book reviews. A world where Game-of-Thrones-quality shows are freely available on YouTube. A world where AI safety research gets the same-level of funding as AI capabilities research. Is this a fantasy world? No, this is the world where people use Dominant Assurance Contracts
If you are already convinced you can make this idea a reality by donating to create a Platform for Dominant Assurance Contracts. If you are not convinced read on.
A few months ago I stumbled across this video. (I highly recommend you watch the video, but if you don’t have time, I’ve summarized the video below).
A good is rival if one person’s use of a good diminishes another person’s ability to benefit from it. Jeans are rival. If I’m wearing a pair of jeans, you can’t wear it at the same time. Asteroid deflection is non-rival. If I deflect an asteroid to protect myself, you are saved with no additional cost.
A good is excludable if people who don’t pay can be easily prevented from using a good. An example of a good that is excludable is a pair of jeans. You can exclude people by locking the jeans in your closet. An example of a good that is non-excludable is asteroid deflection. You cannot prevent the people who did not pay for the asteroid deflection program from benefiting from the asteroid being deflected.
A good which is both rival and excludable is called a private good. A good which is non-rival and non-excludable is called a public good.
(Additionally, goods which are excludable and non-rival are called club goods, and goods which are non-excludable but rival are called common resources. We won’t be focusing on these types of goods, but I’ve mentioned them for completeness)
Excludable | Non-Excludable | |
---|---|---|
Rival | Private Good | Common Resources |
Non-Rival | Club Good | Public Good |
Markets are good at providing private goods because
Public goods challenge markets because
This video stuck with me. The fact the public goods are inefficiently provided by the market seems like the main issue with our civilization. Heck, AI Safety is a public good.
The other thing that stuck is that this seems so solvable. Surely, there is a clever mechanism that can fix this issue? So I went to the Wikipedia page of the Free-rider Problem and scrolled to the bottom, and lo and behold it was just sitting there: Dominant Assurance Contracts invented in 1998 by Alex Tabarrok (yes, the same person who presented the video you just watched). There is only one problem: no one is using them.
(I recommend you watch the first 30 minutes of this video. It’s really good, but if you don’t have time I wrote a short explanation below that you can read instead).
Suppose there are 10 villagers on an unpaved street. Bob the Builder will pave the street for $90. Each villager is willing to contribute up to $15 to have the street paved. Additionally, there is there is a $1 transaction cost to contributing (e.g. from time spent signing forms, from credit card fees, from opportunity cost of not earning interest on that money, etc.).
If the Bob the Builder gets everyone to contribute, each villager will only have to pay $90 / 10 = $9 and profit $15 - $9 - $1 = $5. However, one of the villagers, Free-riding Frank, is hesitant to contribute. Consider Frank’s decision table:
(Frank’s Profit, Others’ Profit) | Others Don’t Contribute | Others Contribute |
---|---|---|
Frank Doesn’t Contribute | (0, 0) | (15, 4) |
Frank Contributes | (-1, 0) | (5, 5) |
Looking at the table and holding the others strategy fixed, Free-riding Frank realizes that the dominant strategy in this game is to not contribute (0 vs −1 and 15 vs 5). Of course, everyone else in the village realizes this too and Bob is unable to raise the funds to pave the road.
Suppose Bob changes the game to a Dominant Assurance Contract. Dominant Assurance Contracts have two conditions:
Frank’s decision table now looks something like this:
(Frank’s Profit, Others’ Profit) | Others Don’t Contribute | Others Contribute |
---|---|---|
Frank Doesn’t Contribute | (0, 0) | (0, 1) |
Frank Contributes | (1, 0) | (5, 5) |
Looking at the table and holding the others strategy fixed, Free-riding Frank now sees that the dominant strategy in this game is to contribute (0 vs 1 and 0 vs 5). Of course, everyone else in the village realizes this too and the road gets paved!
The problem is that the producers of public goods don’t know about them.
Example: Element is building Matrix, an open-standards chat app (i.e. a public good). Their business model is to give away the code/standards for free and sell consulting services. Unfortunately, their competitors have undercut them by selling consulting services without contributing back to the code/standards. On HackerNews you can see their CEO complain about it as “The Tragedy of the Commons”. Except he is not experiencing the tragedy of the commons. He is experiencing the free-rider problem.
If he doesn’t even know what problem he has, he is not going to be able to: google “the free rider problem”; open the Wikipedia page on “the free-rider problem”; scroll to the bottom to find the section titled “Solutions”; and then read about dominant assurance contracts.
People who are trying to produce public goods don’t seem to know that that’s what they are doing, and that dominant assurance contracts are a way to get funding.
My main goal is to give the idea enough airtime so that when people want to produce public goods, the first tool they reach for is a dominant assurance contract.
I only know of four attempts done in the wild (tell me if you know about more).
1 ⁄4 doesn’t seem so good. Dominant assurance contracts work in theory so what is going on?
The theoretical model of Dominant Assurance Contracts assumes away some things that you have to deal with in the real word
I believe the pricing problem can be solved by prediction markets. Book Review, Dark Mode and Berkeley House Dinner all had prediction markets on whether they’d reach their target. The markets were at 90%, 10%, 45%. These probabilities seem consistent with how much money each of the projects raised.
Before we launch a project we could run a multiple-choice prediction market on manifold: “The Project will raise $X”, “The Project will not raise $X”, “The Project will not launch or will launch with a price different from $X”. Only if “The Project will raise $X” is sufficiently high, will we launch the project.
This problem is not unique to dominant assurance contracts. So it can be solved in the same way everyone else does it.
A cool idea is to partner with someone with expertise in marketing. The advertiser can put up the collateral for the refund bonus. If the project succeeds the producer can give them a cut of the funds raised. In this way, the advertiser is incentivized to make the project to succeed.
I think having a progress bar showing how many people have pledged so far is incredibly important to reach the target.
In some sense, with a progress bar, the refund bonus rewards people for providing information on whether the project is likely to reach it’s funding goal.
I suspect the Book Review project would have worked if there was a progress bar.
Personally I think framing it as “You get a Refund Bonus as gratitude for supporting our project which we are very sorry we are unable to deliver” rather than “If you pledge you could win $5. Buy now. ” can make it seem less like a scam.
Having a progress bar also makes it seem less like a scam since it makes it easier for people to predict if the project is going to succeed or fail.
If you price your project correctly (with the help of prediction markets), market it successfully, phrase the refund bonus in a way that it does not seem like a scam and have a progress bar with a list of people who’ve already pledged, then it’s very likely that it will reach it’s target because:
You’re collectively paying for $629 dollars for 1 month of my time to make this idea a reality. (I don’t live in the Bay Area so my cost of living is low). I don’t really need the money. I’m doing this as a experiment to test that dominant assurance contracts work. I’ll likely ask for additional funding in the future to implement more features after the first month, and for specific expenses as they come up.
The plan is to create a website where public-good producers can create a page that
The website is essentially already done (my prototype just has my project hard-coded). I just need to flesh it out so that other people can upload their projects.
The main thing I’m going to doing is looking for people who want to create public goods and getting feedback from them on the platform (if that’s you please join the Refund Bonus Discord or contact me in some other way)
Additionally I want to try some cool things which might not work out like
You haven’t been paying attention. Unless I’ve priced this contract wrong, if you don’t pay it doesn’t happen. If you don’t pay, I don’t meet the goal, everyone gets refunded, I go back to my boring day job, and we continue to live in a world where public goods are under-provisioned.
It seems unlikely. The Dominant Assurance Contract paper came out in 1998. And 25 years later, I seem to be the first person to commit to getting it off the ground. You will probably have to wait a while before someone else comes.
If you want to live in a world with no ads or paywalls; a world where open-source software gets the same level of funding as proprietary software; a world where people can freely reuse ideas and music without paying royalties; a world where people get payed for writing book reviews; a world where Game-of-Thrones-quality shows are freely available on Youtube; a world where AI safety research gets the same-level of funding as AI capabilities research, then please pledge some money towards this.
Also please join the Refund Bonus Discord or contact me in some other way if your interested in:
If we go back to our earlier example, without a refund bonus, due to transaction costs, both “Don’t Contribute” and “Contribute” are both equilibriums (0 vs −1 and 0 vs 5). The refund bonus removes “Don’t Contribute” from the equilibrium.
(Frank’s Profit, Others’ Profit) | Others Don’t Contribute | Others Contribute |
---|---|---|
Frank Doesn’t Contribute | (0, 0) | (0, −1) |
Frank Contributes | (-1, 0) | (5, 5) |
I don’t think enough people are working on this problem. Alex Tabarrok publish his paper on dominant assurance contracts in 1998. Kickstarter was founded in 2009, 11 years later. To this day their are no platforms for dominant assurance contracts to fund public goods.
Most things funded on Kickstarter aren’t even public goods! Their stated mission is to “help bring creative projects to life”. They are even trying to solve the free-rider problem! They just happen to be using a similar mechanism.
I agree dominant assurance contracts are a small improvement, but small improvements add up and almost nobody is working on this!
They are. Here are some successful open-source projects funded by Kickstarter:
Here is an unsuccessful project
Akira got 38% of their target funding. I’d be willing to bet that if they use dominant assurance contracts they would have succeeded.
Apparently 79% of projects that raised more than 20% of their goal were successfully funded. The refund bonus provides the necessary kick (hehe) that gets twice as many projects over the line.
Again, I think the main problem is that people don’t know that assurance contracts (dominant or otherwise) can be used to fund public goods.
Yes! I’m not trying to make a bazillion dollars. I just want more public goods! If Kickstarter copies this idea that would be great! Less work for me!
… AI Capabilities just scale with compute, where as we don’t know how to scale AI Safety. The problem is not funding, and even if it there was a dominant assurance contract for “$1 000 000 000 to solve the alignment problem” there is no guarantee that whoever gets the money will solve the alignment problem.
Yes, there is a information problem when funding research things like AI Safety. We don’t have the information on whether the researcher’s research will be any good. But guess what: information is a public good! That means that it’s currently underfunded. Dominant assurance contracts can bridge that funding gap.
How do we fund information? Of the top of my head a bunch of things come to mind
Of course, there are other ways to fund public goods, but they all have their own problems.
Probably the main method to privately produce public goods is by running ads on goods you give away for free. The main issue with this is that ads pay a fraction of a cent per view. That means that you can only fund low-quality/cheap goods. To see this, compare videos on YouTube with series on HBO.
With taxes you face a symmetric problem to the free-rider problem: the forced-rider problem. Think of someone who doesn’t use a car, but still pays taxes to maintain the roads.
Funding public good through taxes also suffer from lack of market-pricing mechanism. Government spending doesn’t have to pass the market test that a dominant assurance contract has to pass, creating wasteful spending.
Impact certificates suffer from the free-rider problem. There isn’t any incentive (other than altruism) to buy an impact certificate. One can just free-ride on the results of the impact project, and let the initial investor go bankrupt.
I think impact certificates are trying to solve the problem of information asymmetry rather than funding. It’s possible that they could be combined with dominant assurance contracts in some way, but I’m not sure how.
A Club Good is a good that is non-rival but excludable. An example would be a subscription to HBO or Microsoft Office. It costs practically nothing on the margin to give an additional person access to HBO or Microsoft Office (all the costs were upfront in production) so these goods are non-rival. However, since HBO and Microsoft charge for these goods they are excludable.
Of course, there is piracy. So the first problem is that it’s actually difficult to turn a public good into a club good, and so the free-rider problem persists.
Secondly, it’s inefficient to exclude people. If you would pay $5 to watch Game of Thrones but the HBO subscription is $15, then $5 of surplus is being lost (it costs HBO $0 to let you watch Game of Thrones).
This is a type of club good.
From personal experience, I think this works okay for art where the patrons have a parasocial relationship with the artist. This seems to work less well for impersonal stuff like software.
Additionally, it’s easy for Buccaneer Bob to sign up to your Patreon and then upload your products to a piracy website. Free-riding Frank won’t bother to sign up to your Patreon, he’ll just download your products off a piracy website.
If you price a dominant assurance contract correctly, Free-rider Frank is forced to pay.
The idea with micropayments is something like “cost per marginal unit is a fraction of a cent so we should make it possible for people to pay fractions of cents.” I think this doesn’t work because the cost of fraud is higher than a fraction of a cent. Also, the cost of me thinking “Is this worth 0.01c?” is higher than a fraction of a cent. It’s just better to treat such things as non-rival.
The main issue with an assurance contract without a refund bonus is that “not contributing” is an equilibrium, especially if their are substantial transaction costs. I already explained this above.
Public goods are under-provisioned by the market due to the free-rider problem. Dominant assurance contracts solve the free-rider problem. Nobody is using dominant assurance contracts. To solve this problem, and simultaneously test if dominant assurance contracts work, I created a dominant assurance contract to fund a platform for creating dominant assurance contracts.
There’s still no incentive for the freerider to sign up if the limit would otherwise be reached.
Instead what this solves is the coordination problem. Prosocial people want to fund various markets, but it’s a waste of time doing this if nobody else joins in. The dominant assurance contract makes this worth it either way, so it’s easier for markets to get off the ground to the point where it looks like they’ll probably make it.
Which is why crowdfunding campaigns use an amount of money as the goal instead of the amount of backers. But if you use funding-goal instead of a backers-goal, and people collectively value what you offer more than what you ask for it, then you still have the possibility of free riding, because it would be possible for the campaign to succeed without everybody (I think this is fine).
The goal isn’t to eliminate free-riding, it’s to prevent projects from failing because people try to free ride, and these are very different things, because the latter means you’re willing to tolerate free-riders as long as the project gets funded, and former means you’re unwilling to tolerate free-riding even if the project could otherwise be funded.
So, though DACs do reduce free-riding, and do probably allow people to donate less each and still reach the goal, they don’t completely solve free riding because you’d rarely want to use them in such a way where they do (which is why you implement refund compensation but don’t require certain amount of participation or set the price so high that everyone would need to participate).
As @Yair Halberstadt said, the problem this actually solve is the coordination problem faced by people who want to back the project if it succeeds, but don’t want to pay the cost of backing a failed project. In that sense, refund compensation is a very natural extension of of the Kickstarter model, because it simply recognizes that people need to be refunded for their effort and not just their money.
About your element/matrix example, the problem is indeed free-riding, but DACs would only solve the problem if he wouldn’t keep developing it unless he got a certain amount of funding (which would make it a coordination problem). If he doesn’t want to condition the development on a certain level of funding, then funding will be based only on the goodwill of people. So DACs also don’t solve cases where a reward is deserved, but you’re gonna do the thing regardless.
And because of the title, would a DAC be a good way to raise money for asteroid deflection? Definitely not as a way to try to make everyone participate in funding the deflection. It’s a good solution only if there’s a minimum amount of funding or backers you can do it with, and with any less than that you may as well not bother. But that doesn’t seem like a good idea. If you get $5 or 1 person less than you asked for ate you just gonna do nothing? Or would you rather try anyway and die with dignity?
Public/private goods
I think the focus on public goods in the post is a bit confusing. Not because it’s a problem to have and offer that as the main motivation for this, but because it makes it seem like it’s only relevant for public goods, where it’s still as relevant for private goods if there’s a big upfront cost to producing any at all, so you have to have a minimum number of customers. For example, designing a product is a large cost that you have to pay upfront, but it also doesn’t scale with the amount of products sold. So it makes sense to say ‘I will sell this only if there’s enough buyers to cover the design cost’. Most crowdfunding campaigns for private goods are exactly of this type, and would benefit almost as much from refund compensation as public good campaigns (and it should sadded us that they fail due to a coordination problems as well, because even though it’s a private good it’s still lost value).
I agree with this comment except for these two pointsAbout your element/matrix example, the problem is indeed free-riding, but DACs would only solve the problem if he wouldn’t keep developing it unless he got a certain amount of funding (which would make it a coordination problem). If he doesn’t want to condition the development on a certain level of funding, then funding will be based only on the goodwill of people. So DACs also don’t solve cases where a reward is deserved, but you’re gonna do the thing regardless.
I don’t think he is going to do it regardless. Presumably if he doesn’t get enough money he has to shut-down his company completely or reduce the amount he spends on open-source and focus on the more profitable consulting side of the business. If DACs were used they could invest more in the open source.
I think the focus on public goods in the post is a bit confusing. Not because it’s a problem to have and offer that as the main motivation for this, but because it makes it seem like it’s only relevant for public goods, where it’s still as relevant for private goods if there’s a big upfront cost to producing any at all.
Private goods already have a mechanism to solve this problem: investment. That’s why I think DACs are not that relevant for private goods.
In the case where he has a minimum amount below which he is unwilling to continue development, then I agree a DAC would help raise that amount. Investment solves the funding problem, it doesn’t solve the problem of making sure you have enough buyers. And if you can’t solve the latter then you might not be able to get investors either (cause they also want to know you have enough buyers). That’s the problem Kickstarter solves, and DACs would solve wven better, in addition to funding.
Dominant assurance contracts seems gambling-like/scam-like the same way that crypto-currency does. The top comment on the Berkeley House Dinner Project is “this is a dollar-auction (AKA scam)”, and the second top comment is “Surely this is illegal?”
I don’t see anywhere in your post where you address the question of whether this is actually legal, though? An offer that if someone gives you money then (depending on factors outside of that person’s control) you may give them double their money back sounds like the kind of thing societies tend to regulate heavily. For example, in the US, I think it is possible that this would pass the Howey test to be considered a security?
I think it fails 3 and 4 simultaneously. There is no “expectation of profit to be derived from the efforts of others”. If the contract succeeds then others make an effort but you do not make a profit. If the contract fails you make a profit, but not from the efforts of others.
Not a lawyer, but I’m not sure it’s so clear cut. If I buy because I expect the contract not to tip, I’m expecting profit (3) derived from your efforts in setting up the contract (4).
Maybe we shouldn’t call it a Refund Bonus but something like “Attention Compensation”. I would say that you are expecting to profit (3) derived from your efforts of reading the contract and agreeing to pledge and then not actually getting what you paid for (not 4). Personally I think it’s irrational to give money expecting a DAC to fail. make-yass made a post about this. I think the long-run social equilibrium is that people realize that it’s dumb to gamble on DACs failing and don’t do it.
In traditional charitable enterprises, we just call it “a donor gift.”Agree, this is important. When I wrote about this I didn’t consider that it might be illegal. I’m quite ignorant of the law, but I recently wrote my thought on legality of refund bonuses here. tl;dr, I think it’s legal, but there’s a bunch of things you have to do for it to be legal. And I now think this is the main reason no crowdfunding platform has ever used refund bonuses, not that they don’t know about it or don’t think it’s a good idea. I would really like if someone law-savvy would write up an explanation of the legality of refund bonuses. I’d even be willing to contribute money towards that.
I am not a lawyer, but I think that sometimes the problem can be avoided by returning something other than cash. Sometimes, just having an expiration date makes the difference. You give me $1; if the project fails I give you a $2 coupon you can spend in Walmart you need to spend before December 2023. (Of course, ask a lawyer about the details. I am just pointing at a possible angle of approach.)
Does “Kickstarter but they refund you if the project doesn’t meet its goal” exist? I think not — that might get you some of the gains of a DAC platform. Also, what does PayPal’s TOS say about this? I seriously considered building something similar, and Stripe only approves “crowdfunding” if you have their written approval.
Does “Kickstarter but they refund you if the project doesn’t meet its goal” exist?That’s just Kickstarter. You already only pay if the project hits its funding goal.
This is a interesting idea, but your example oversells it substantially. Future iterations need to not do this, or you’ll sound like a huckster and not get support. If all ten people on the street have to contribute, everyone knows for sure that they won’t get what they want if they don’t contribute. No payback is necessary; free riding is impossible. That’s the easy case. When you just need some amount of money rather than every single individual to contribute, it’s quite possible to free ride.
You haven’t been paying attention. Unless I’ve priced this contract wrong, if you don’t pay it doesn’t happen.
This is egregiously wrong. You can’t possibly know that this contract will fail if each individual reader of this sentence doesn’t contribute. This is the distinction from the example you’ve used. So I agree with the other comments that this does not fix the freerider problem. At all. Which is the big problem, not the frictional costs of pledging. I think you’ve got to fix that terrible logic in future versions, or you’ll sound dishonest. I still pledged fifty bucks, because improving crowdsourcing like Kickstarter even marginally is a worthy goal! And the frictional cost is still a problem, so overcoming it will help.
I’m fully funded! In fact, as of writing. I have nearly 3x more funding than I asked for! The money really started rolling in after Alex Tabarrok plugged my project on marginal revolution, which I did not expect. I’m not sure why people continued to give me money after the project was fully funded but I’m very thankful. (Of course, the more money I get the longer I can work on the project increasing the chance of success). The fundraising only officially ends 15 September, so I’m not going to give a full report until then. I was hoping to do some neglected chores while the campaign ran, but since I’m already fully-funded, I feel I can’t leave people hanging. So right now I’m collecting people who would like to use my platform to produce public goods to solicit requirements from them. If you’re interested join our Discord if you haven’t already.
Wonderful that you’re working on this! I’m with AI Safety Impact Markets, and I suspect that we will need a system like this eventually. We haven’t received a lot of feedback to the effect yet, so I haven’t prioritized it, but there are at least two applications for it (for investors and (one day, speculatively) for impact buyers/retrofunders). We’re currently addressing it with a bonding curve auction of sorts, which incentivizes donors to come in early, so that they’re also not so incentivized to wait each other out. The incentive structures are different, though, so maybe a combination would be nice. That last link links to an article that links to GiveWell’s donor’s dilemma. Some people outside EA who I’ve talked to were surprised by it. They had found that donors flock to uncontroversially good donation opportunities and don’t try to save their donations for niche projects. I’m thinking that might be because they donate to look good to others, which works better if they actually look good to others and not weird. So maybe DACs are mostly needed for coordination among utilitarians or some range of consequentialists? Then again these are different problems – freeriding because you want the benefits of the public good for free vs. freeriding so that you can use your funds for a niche project. Both defections in assurance games though. Sorry if I missed it in the article, but who are the parties you would like to get on board to put up the refund bonuses? Can you bootstrap them by using DACs to fundraise for bigger and bigger refund bonuses? Are you aware of any issues with securities law, since people can make monetary profits off refund bonuses? I might be able to get you in touch with someone who knows these things when it comes to the US. I imagine (no idea really) that the law of the country of the person who starts a fundraiser will be what matters legally. Can you maybe just pick out a charity fundraising platform that has funding thresholds and refunds (and is used by consequentialists), put Pol.is on top to rank the projects by how uncontroversial they are, and then offer proportional (to the uncontroversiality) refund bonuses to everyone who contributed to failed fundraisers? Maybe they can apply, prove that they’ve contributed to a failed fundraiser, and get the payout? Maybe, if you’re completely independent of the people who put up the fundraisers, you won’t risk getting them in trouble with the SEC? More philosophically: I think it’s hard to distinguish freeriding from division of labor in economies of scale when there is no explicit coordination. DACs are probably useful in the majority of cases, but there’s a minority of cases where people (usually rather altruistic people) should pick their battles, focus on the stuff where they can make the greatest marginal contribution, and “freeride” on the social change that others effect in other areas. Put differently, I would love a non-speciesist world and a world where funding in AI safety is allocated efficiently. I’m currently working only on the second problem, so one could argue that I’m freeriding on others’ solutions to the first. But in a different sense it’s just a division of labor among people who want to make the world a better place in general. So some seeming freerider problems probably need fixing with DACs, while others might not be problems at all or might be improved with better communication without anyone having to put up a refund bonus. (But money is flexible, so DACs for fundraising are probably robustly useful.) Awesome effort! Please keep us posted of how it’s going! Btw., I think it would be useful to mention what the article is about in the title. I would not have read it (even though I’m very interested in the topic) if Dony hadn’t told me that it’s about DACs!
Thanks for you comment, it’s very helpful.Sorry if I missed it in the article, but who are the parties you would like to get on board to put up the refund bonuses?It would the producer of the public good (e.g. for my project I put up the collateral).
Can you bootstrap them by using DACs to fundraise for bigger and bigger refund bonuses?Possibly? I’m not sure why you’d do that?
Are you aware of any issues with securities law, since people can make monetary profits off refund bonuses?
I disagree that a Refund Bonus is a security. It’s a refund. To me it’s when you buy something, but it comes broken, so the store gives you a voucher to make up for your troubles.
I imagine (no idea really) that the law of the country of the person who starts a fundraiser will be what matters legally.
I’m in South Africa but from what I can tell, if you work with US dollars and do something illegal the FBI will come after you, so I wouldn’t be confident that only South African law applies.
Can you maybe just pick out a charity fundraising platform that has funding thresholds and refunds (and is used by consequentialists), and refund bonuses to everyone who contributed to failed fundraisers?
This is actually a cool idea. I don’t know how I’d manage to get people’s details for giving refund without co-operating with the fundraising platform, and my impression is that most platforms are hesitant to do things like this. If you know of a platform that would be keen on trying this, please tell me!
Put differently, I would love a non-speciesist world and a world where funding in AI safety is allocated efficiently. I’m currently working only on the second problem, so one could argue that I’m freeriding on others’ solutions to the first.
I don’t quite understand this point. You could work on AI Safety and donate to animal charities if you don’t want to free-ride.
Btw., I think it would be useful to mention what the article is about in the title. I would not have read it (even though I’m very interested in the topic) if Dony hadn’t told me that it’s about DACs!
You’re right. I didn’t want the title to just be “Dominant Assurance Contracts” because I assumed that most people have never heard of them and tried to come up with something more interesting, but maybe enough people on lesswrong have heard of them so I should probably be more straight forward.
I disagree that a Refund Bonus is a security. It’s a refund. To me it’s when you buy something, but it comes broken, so the store gives you a voucher to make up for your troubles.
Then perhaps we should call it ‘Refund Compensation’ instead. I’d much rather if refund compensation didn’t fall under securities laws and everyone could offer it hassle-free.
I really like that. It draws attention to the fact that the “bonus” is compensation for time and effort spent on trying to buy a product that was never delivered.
It would the producer of the public good (e.g. for my project I put up the collateral).Oh, got it! Thanks!
Possibly? I’m not sure why you’d do that?
I thought you’d be fundraising to offer refund compensation to others to make their fundraisers more likely to succeed. But if the project developer themself put up the compensation, it’s probably also an important signal or selection effect in the game theoretic setup.
I disagree that a Refund Bonus is a security.
Yeah, courts decide that in the end. Howey Test: money: yes; common enterprise: yes; expectation of profit: sometimes; effort of others: I don’t know, not really? The size of the payout is not security-like, but I don’t know if that matters. All very unclear. Profit: I imagine people will collect statistics on how close to funded campaigns can still be a day before they close so that they still fail in (say) 90% of the cases. Then they blindly invest $x into all campaigns that are still $x away from that threshold on their last day. I imagine the courts may find that if someone goes to such efforts to exploit the system, they were probably not tricked into doing so. Plus there is the question of what effort of others we could possibly be referring to. But even if the courts in the end decide that you’re right and it’s not a security, the legal battle with the SEC alone will be very expensive… They keep expanding their own heuristic for what they think is a security (not up to them to decide). They’ve even started to ignore the “expectation of profit” entirely (with stablecoins). But perhaps you can find a way to keep the people who run the fundraisers in the clear and keep your company in South Africa (where I know the laws even less though). If the fundraisers are on a mainstream blockchain, the transactions are public, so you (outside of the US) could manage the refund compensation on behalf of the project developers and then pay refunds according to the public records on the blockchain. That way, no one could prove that a particular project developer is a member in your system… except maybe if they make “honeypot” contributions I suppose. Perhaps you can have a separate fund from which you reward contributors to projects you like regardless of whether they’re members. If a honeypot contributor gets a refund, they won’t know whether it’s because the project developer is a member of your org or because you selected their project without them knowing about it.
This is actually a cool idea. I don’t know how I’d manage to get people’s details for giving refund without co-operating with the fundraising platform, and my impression is that most platforms are hesitant to do things like this. If you know of a platform that would be keen on trying this, please tell me!
Yes… You could talk with Giveth about it. They’re using blockchains, so perhaps you can build on top of them without them having to do anything. But what I’ve done in the past is that people sign up with my platform, get a code, and put the code in their pubic comment that they can attach to a contribution on the third-party platform. Then if they want to claim any rights attached to the contribution from me, I check that the code is the right one, and if it is, believe them that they’re either the person who made the contribution or that the person who made the contribution wanted to gift it to them.
I don’t quite understand this point. You could work on AI Safety and donate to animal charities if you don’t want to free-ride.
Well, let’s say I barely have the money to pay for my own cost of living or that I consider a number of AI safety orgs to also be the even-more-cost-effective uses of my money.
But what I’ve done in the past is that people sign up with my platform, get a code, and put the code in their pubic comment that they can attach to a contribution on the third-party platform. Then if they want to claim any rights attached to the contribution from me, I check that the code is the right one, and if it is, believe them that they’re either the person who made the contribution or that the person who made the contribution wanted to gift it to them.
Oh cool, that’s a good idea. Then you can piggy back off existing crowdfunding platforms instead of making your own one.
people sign up with my platform,Do you have a link? It sounds cool. I want to check it out.
Well, let’s say I barely have the money to pay for my own cost of living or that I consider a number of AI safety orgs to also be the even-more-cost-effective uses of my money.I think I see your point. I agree that DACs don’t solve this type of free-riding.
Love the idea (contributed 10 dollars), but I don’t love the title—it feels a little clickbaity (I expected an article about asteroid deflection, not about DACs).
Yeah, something descriptive like “A platform to fund public goods using dominant assurance contracts” or “A refund bonus crowdfunding platform to subsidize public goods” would be better in my opinion (and the jargon wouldn’t be a problem in this community).
I’m somewhat flabbergasted that no one has mentioned radicalxChange or quadratic funding. They’re a solution that doesn’t force the producer to take on all the risks of failure, at the cost of needing a centralized pot of money.
The cost of needing a centralized pot of money is a big cost, and the requirement to have several projects at once, make it a solution to a very different class of problems. That’s probably the reason it wasn’t mentioned, but still, thanks for mentioning it because I didn’t know about it. Upvoted. It would be interesting, though, to try to combine the two ideas. You can add an option to the platform described in the post to pledge money to a centralized pool that’s used to match pledges people make (and if they’re refunded than the refund bonus on your matching pledge goes either to the pool or back to you). That way can you support the production of highly desired goods without having to actually choose by yourself which goods.
For these reasons, it’s hard for me to get excited about DACs.
There is probably a narrow band of projects where DACs are make-or-break, and because you’re excited about them, I think it’s great if you get the funding you’re hoping for and succeed in normalizing them. Prove me wrong, by all means!